The Project Gutenberg eBook of A Speech on the Principles of Finance This ebook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included with this ebook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you are not located in the United States, you will have to check the laws of the country where you are located before using this eBook. Title: A Speech on the Principles of Finance Author: Victoria C. Woodhull Release date: August 9, 2021 [eBook #66026] Language: English Credits: Richard Tonsing and the Online Distributed Proofreading Team at https://www.pgdp.net (This file was produced from images generously made available by The Internet Archive) *** START OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK A SPEECH ON THE PRINCIPLES OF FINANCE *** A SPEECH ON THE PRINCIPLES OF FINANCE, BY VICTORIA C. WOODHULL, DELIVERED AT COOPER INSTITUTE, NEW YORK CITY, THURSDAY, AUGUST 3, 1871. NEW YORK: WOODHULL, CLAFLIN & CO., No. 41 BROAD STREET. 1871. THE PRINCIPLES OF FINANCE. MONEY! IS IT A PRINCIPLE OR A PROPERTY? To the careful student of history, there is a very great deal more to be considered than the mere political facts that stand as landmarks along the path of progress which the nations have traversed since the plains of Iran poured forth their hosts westward. These facts are the mere externals that adorn the pages of historic lore, and embellish the memories of the great men who have lived in and moved the world at various times in various nations, or which clothe the lives of tyrants and usurpers with their just reward. The superficial student of history cares only for the _results_ of the evolution of nations—for the _fact_ that Sesostris was the greatest of Egyptian kings; or that Semiramis rose by her military sagacity from the rank of a mean official’s wife to be, first, the Queen of Ninas, and afterward, to be the Assyrian Queen, who should march an army of three millions men across the Indus to conquer the Indian King. Running down the course of events, he traces the rise and fall of nations—after Assyria then Egypt, next Persia, Greece, Rome and then the Dark Ages, out of whose womb was evolved modern Europe; and, lastly, the birth, development, struggle and recovery of the most remarkable nation which has yet arisen in the world. Behind these facts, which are but results, lie the real motor powers of history; and they are deeper, broader and more important than is that which _they_ evolve. There is an external and an internal phase to everything existent in the world. Up to _this_ generation the external has apparently borne the more prominent part in determining what should be next. But _now_ the analytic age has begun, wherein facts do not suffice; wherein new systems, new theories, new philosophies and even new religions are constructed, not by an examination of the _errors_ of what has been, but by the _discovery_ and _application_ of the principles, the powers, which underlie those errors. Heretofore there has been no inquiry made by the rulers of the people into the general principles of government. It was sufficient that there was a government maintained, the governors caring for little but the power to compel the people to do their bidding. But it is beginning to dawn upon the minds of those who have something more than a selfish interest in humanity that there _is a science_ of government; aye, even that there is a science of society: and such minds are endeavoring by the deepest researches to discover the principles of these sciences. In our government, the principle of individual rights is theoretically held, though in its application government still interferes with those rights. The legitimate functions of a government, based upon the rights of every individual over whom its power is exercised, are limited to the _duties_ that will best _subserve_ and _protect_ the interests of individuals. The proper understanding and practice of these functions is the most important thing for a people to arrive at, but, having arrived at this as the basis of all the relations of the people, the scientific construction of the various departments of the complete superstructure which is to cover all the public interests of all the people, as well as to maintain their private interests intact, can be begun. After the general principles of government are properly formulated in Constitutions and vitality given them by laws, a correct, a scientific financial system stands _next_ in importance. If a country have a true system of _government_, and do not have a true system of _finance_, it can never attain to any _permanent_ prosperity. Literally speaking, finance is a _part_ of government; since, in organizing it, means for its support are among the first considerations. Hence it is plain, if there are principles of government, so must there also be principles of finance. It has never been pretended, so far as I know, even by the profoundest political economists, who are sticklers for the gold standard, that any financial systems the world has ever known were developed by the scientific application of self-evident truths, which is the nature of principles. The various systems of which use has been made were simply _experimental_, devised for _politic_ reasons, as the _best_ methods to meet the exigencies of the times in which they were required. Instance the Greenback, the necessity for which was such as to shake the nation to its very centre, and to fill the minds of all patriots with a dread foreboding. If there have been no scientific money systems in vogue, and it now comes out that the world has arrived at that degree of advancement wherein _policy_ should give way to _principles_, even in finance, there can be nothing gained by going back to review the errors, failures and fallacies of the past. Nothing valuable can be gained by wading through the almost innumerable statistics which have accumulated to a sufficiently great extent to bewilder the most comprehensive intellects. Having for ten years been deeply engaged in studying the principles of government, I learned that no system of government could be perfect unless its financial department was perfected; therefore I have frequently endeavored to solve the financial problems which statistics propose, but _invariably_ failed to learn anything that even promised to look well as a basis for a new and improved system, to say nothing of its promises in operation. The conclusion was inevitable, that there have been _no_ acknowledged or even known, fundamental principles of finance operating in _any_ of the many systems of the many nations, and that the so-called money of the world _is not now, nor ever was_, money, in the scientific sense of that term. All the statistics, failures and errors of the past, with which the history of money abounds, being of no value, must be utterly ignored in any inquiry which proposes to predicate a natural and scientific money, as distinguished from arbitrary inventions, devised to meet the various exigencies of nations in their growth, prime and decay. And _any_ person who proposes to teach finance, or a new system, by arraying before you the evidences of the past, contained in figures amounting to billions of dollars, simply proposes to try _another experiment_, to _culminate_ in another failure. Therefore I shall present no principals, per cents. and compounded amounts, except, perhaps, as examples to illustrate the mathematical impossibilities of the fallacious theories by which financiers have attempted to dazzle the world, but who have only succeeded in accumulating in the hands of a very select few that which by an exact justice should belong to, and be distributed among, the people generally. In order to intelligently discuss and arrive at legitimate conclusions regarding the question of money, it should be _first_ determined just what is to be involved in the discussion; for around this, as around all other general things, there has been such a mass of rubbish and extraneous matter aggregated that the main question is always in danger of being lost sight of, unless this be first removed and the real issue left clearly exposed. Most of the confusion which follows the attempts to solve the money question arises out of the fact that the _same_ words in the mouths of _different_ people do not mean the _same_ things, or that _different_ words are used by _different_ people to mean the _same_ thing. If there are two words in common use to represent similar objects, but which, upon close analysis, _do not_ represent precisely the same thing, it is better that _one_ of them be discarded. It is necessary, therefore, to settle, prior to the beginning of this argument, _precisely_ what the several terms _do_ mean which are prominently in use in connection with the money question. It is, perhaps, near the truth to say that this settlement is the argument. Very few persons have any well-defined comprehension of what is the _real_ significance of the terms _gold_, _money_, _currency_, _intrinsic value_ and _wealth_. If these words are analyzed, what do they scientifically represent? Gold is a product of the earth only to be originally obtained by labor and expense, and both practically and scientifically bears like relations _to_ labor that all other things do which are produced _by_ labor; and none other. But there has been an importance attached to gold which has not been accorded to _any other_ product of labor. It has been coined and called money, because it was coined, and by custom and common acceptance made an _arbitrary_ standard of value, which _none_ of its qualities warrant when subjected to analysis, as will be shortly shown. Gold bears the same relation to _real_ money that a religious theory bears to _real_ religion, which theory, when comprehended by the intellect of the people, loses its value as a substitute for real religion; but which, until comprehension comes, it is better to have than to have none at all. So also with gold. It has in _theory_ been considered as _money_; but when a _true_ money comes to be comprehended, it will lose its value as a substitute therefor, and sink to its proper sphere among the other products of labor. It is altogether probable that gold was the very best substitute for money during that part of the world’s evolution wherein people were guided and controlled by policy and before principles were recognized as that which should govern, let their action lead where it might. As the world is now beginning to act from _principle_, for the sake of the _truth_, so also must they now begin to formulate the principle of money for the sake of the principle. Wealth is whatever is produced by labor which adds to the _comforts_, the _happiness_ or the _life_ of man; and everything that does this, either directly or indirectly, has intrinsic value—that is, has the capacity to bless mankind. Wealth may, and should, be divided into two kinds, namely, _permanent_ wealth and _transitory_ wealth. Permanent wealth consists of all those products of labor which are not themselves _transferable_ into life, comfort or happiness, but which may at all times be _exchanged_ for that which is thus transferable into that which can be used to continue life. Gold, silver and precious stones are among the best illustrations there are of permanent wealth. Transitory wealth consists of all those products of labor of which direct use is made to maintain life or to add to its comforts and happiness, and which, _by_ such process, are absorbed _into_ and become _a part of_ the life of humanity. Transitory wealth, it will be seen, is much the more important of the two, since, if people only possessed permanent wealth, their life could not be continued an hour by it, unless there were a possibility of exchanging it for the necessities of life. It would seem that _all_ kinds of wealth are intrinsically valuable, since its various kinds may be either _directly_ used to maintain life or may be _exchanged_ for those which will maintain life. Wealth and intrinsic value, then, mean the same thing. But what does the term _money_ mean: or has it no necessary significance in the inquiry? There was a time when there was no such _thing_ or _word_ as money; but at that time there was life to continue, for which wealth was necessary. It seems that _wealth_ had existence before _money_ was thought of. Wealth is substance, of which money is the principle or representative, but which, in itself, has no intrinsic value. Money is an invention made to _represent_ wealth, or value, in order that its various kinds may be exchanged with facility, or that they may be exchanged without the absolute and direct and immediate receipt and delivery of one product of labor for another product of labor. All the products of labor may be exchanged _directly_, and without the use of any representative or go-between, which for the time being stands representative of the one or the other, but _not so well_ at all times and under all circumstances. Money is _anything_ which stands representative of any product of labor; that is, that can be made use of to facilitate the exchange of any of the results of labor, which are wealth. A representative of anything cannot be the thing itself, therefore, if money is a representative of wealth it is not itself wealth. Were A, B and C to at all times exchange their products between themselves by _direct transfer_, they would have _no use_ for money; they would exchange—deliver and receive—_actual_ values. But when A desires from B some of his products, himself not having on hand any of his products which B desires, he receives from B his value and gives him his representative of value—his note—promising that at a future time he will deliver B the _actual_ value which he desires. _Currency_ is only a _form_ of money, the same as _gold_ is only a form of wealth; and in the same manner that gold is wealth, is currency money. Money being the principle of representation in exchange, everything of which use is made to facilitate exchange in the form of representative value is money. Anything which can be transferred from one party to another, anything that is negotiable which is not actual value of itself, is money. This includes not only all currency, bank notes, but also bills of exchange, the ledger and bonds. These are _all_ representatives of wealth, _all_ demands for payment at a future time of a certain specified sum, and consequently are money. It is quite evident that, with the terms _wealth_ and _money_, we have all the necessary distinctions which should enter into the abstract question of finance. All other terms are but names for separate kinds or forms of these terms, to be made use of when they respectively arise in making exchanges. Now, every one must at once concede that that which best represents all of the products of labor will also best _exchange_ them, and is therefore the _best_ money. It is _equally clear_ that gold in _no way_ represents _any_ labor but that which produces it. If gold were a true representative of the results of _all_ other labor, except that which produces it, would it not also be apparent that _such_ labor must be _equal_ to _all_ other labor. Were gold a thousand times more valuable than it is held to be, it would not _even then_ be able to represent all other values. Therefore, gold is a _false_ standard of value, a _false_ representative of wealth. Many people think and speak as if gold would be of no use to this country if it were to come into disuse as _money_; that we should entirely lose it as _wealth_; the very reverse is really true, since we should have just the same quantity of gold that we _now_ have, to be used for the _same_ purposes for which it is now required, to wit: to export to other countries in exchange for imports. Suppose our imports to amount to a thousand millions dollars per annum, and that we export cotton, corn and pork to that amount, what use would we have for gold except to loan other countries, and could we not _loan_ it as _gold_, taking their representatives of value for it equally as well as though it were coined into money, having the seal and stamp of the government? It is well known that we do not export gold to Europe as so many American dollars, but as so much gold, by weight of a certain degree of fineness, the stamp of the government attesting to that degree. Again: Suppose that we had no cotton, corn or pork to give in exchange for our imports, and that we produced a thousand millions dollars’ worth of gold per annum, should we not be _equally_ well conditioned to trade with Europe? It is seen that the real character and qualities of gold are the same as are those of any other product of labor, which we can exchange direct, for other products of labor which we want more than we do the gold. If at any time the balance of trade is _against_ us, and we have _no_ cotton, corn, pork, gold or _anything else_ to make it good, we must then make it good by our representatives of value—our bonds—to be converted when we shall have these products. This process has been actually going on ever since we began to export bonds, either national, state, county, city, railroad or bonds of other incorporated companies. Now, is it not _perfectly_ evident that we have not only produced by labor what we have exported, which we have been pleased to denominate merchandise, but also that we have produced all the gold that has been exported; and in this connection is it not just as much an article of merchandise as is either cotton or corn? Gold cannot at _one_ and the _same_ time be both _money_ and _merchandise_. If _gold_ is money, so also is _wheat_, _cotton_ and _corn_ money, since they perform the same _services_ and possess the same _qualities_ as merchandise that gold does. To be perfectly clear in our conclusions, money must be resolved into its _uses_ and entirely divested of all its _fictitious_ and _irrelevant_ relations. The fact that money is that thing which is made use of to exchange real values must be the initial starting-point, of which sight must never be lost until it is _definitely_ settled what will _best_ perform this service. Anything which can be made use of for _any other purpose whatever_, is _not_ the _best_ thing to be made use of as money; because the demand for such a thing for such other purposes destroys its positive value as money by causing fluctuations in its exchanging power. It is a grave financial error for this country to endeavor to return to gold as money. All the practices under the gold standard have been positive and ample refutations of the arbitrary value accorded to gold. A _dollar_ in gold can only exchange a _dollar_ in value in any other substance; and the practice of issuing a greater amount of bank notes than the bank has gold dollars to redeem them by, is a _legalized_ system to _rob_ the people; since it is _evident_ that a bank having three hundred thousand dollars in notes in circulation, and only one hundred thousand dollars in gold in its vaults, can redeem but _one-third_ of its circulation if it be all presented at once for redemption. All the other securities of a bank, such as its discounts, personal property and real estate, may become of no value, or may be placed out of reach of the holders of its circulation, so that the only _real_ security for its circulation is what it may have in gold in its vaults. Beside, what right has a bank to receive legal interest on three times the amount of its real security? Is not this a most _transparent_ method of _swindling_ the people? Hence I assert that the use of gold as money _always_ results disastrously to the producers of wealth, and _always_ beneficially to those who are permitted to absorb all their productions. Another unanswerable reason why gold cannot answer the requirements of money is found in the _degrees of value_ which belong to different products of labor, and which are _universally_ determined by the sacrifice required to produce them. That is to say, all other things being equal, the _relative_ value of products is determined by the _time_ and _labor_ required to produce them. The increase in the value of manufactured material is in _exact_ proportion to the _time_ required and _wealth_ consumed in their manufacture. The value of gold is determined in _precisely_ the same manner; and it is simply foolishness to assert that the value of gold never changes, or that it has the same purchasing power at all times. Suppose there should be immense fields of gold suddenly developed all over the country, so that it would become as common and plentiful as iron or coal, would it not decrease in value in comparison with other products? That is to say, would an ounce of gold then possess as great a proportionate value to other products as it now does? No one will pretend it. Then gold is just as much the subject of fluctuation as is any other product of labor, and for _just the same_ reasons—demand and supply—which are the great arbitrators of values in all parts of the world. Everybody knows that for a certain quantity of gold a certain quantity of cotton may be obtained, and for a certain quantity of corn, a horse. The fact that the horse is obtainable by the corn does not convert the corn into money, neither does gold any more than the corn become money because the cotton is obtained thereby. The gold for the time is equal in value to the cotton, and so is the corn to the horse. Now, what is required of money is this: Suppose the gold, cotton, corn and the horse to be of equal value, a person possessing an amount of money representing the value of either of the four can, at his discretion, purchase whichever he may choose; since the money would equally represent the gold, cotton, corn and the horse. Anything that may be used for money that will not do the same thing for any variety of the products of labor, values being equal, is not money in any sense of that term. Incidentally in this connection, because it has an indirect bearing upon the question under consideration, I wish to call attention to a mistake that has been productive of more financial ills and consequent injustice to a large proportion of the people, who are the wealth producers, than any other single cause, and that is the fundamental error of making land, wealth, which it is no more entitled to be, scientifically, than gold is to be called money. Wealth is that which is produced. Land exists. All improvements made upon land are wealth; _but the land proper, never_. In this almost fatal mistake—almost fatal to the humanitarian interests of the so-called common people—which is fundamental in its nature, is found the _basis_ upon which rest the vast disparities in the distributions of wealth, and which gives to certain favored individuals the means of realizing vast fortunes without ever resorting to the production of wealth, or of even accumulating it by trafficking in the different kinds of wealth. There are numerous examples of this manner of becoming possessed of riches. People acquire title to lands which, by favorable location, come into great demand and consequently rise in value from _one dollar per acre to hundreds of thousands of dollars per acre_. By what principle of _equity_ and _right_ should _any_ person be entitled to such vast increases in capital invested in land, when it is entirely attributable to the movements of the community which produce it, and in no single particular to the individual? To be so entitled is for the individual to possess advantages over others to which no just communal government should for a moment consent—is to have the right to appropriate to self the results of labor which belong in common to all the people. Such results are against _all_ principles of equity and justice, and is one of the _greatest_, if not _the_ greatest error of the present, regarding the equities of property, and is the foundation and prophecy of all other kinds of monopoly. It occurs to me that an objection may be raised to my argument classing gold as wealth, and defining wealth to be that which can be made use of to minister to life, comfort and happiness; or perhaps to the distinction of permanent and transitory wealth. Gold, as permanent wealth, can only minister to man through its exchange for other valuables of which direct use can be made. It may be said that in _that_ sense gold can legitimately be money. But if there are objectors to this argument, I beg to call their attention to the conclusive fact that gold _can never_ be representative of all other kinds of wealth. It is just as impossible that it should be, as it is that a bridge _one_ hundred feet in length should span a river _five_ hundred feet in width. It must further be remembered that the uses for which money is required demand an invention which can be made use of for _no other_ purpose whatever, and that money is the name of an invention _demanded_ and made for the purpose of _facilitating_ exchanges—for making them easy, _convenient_ and _adaptable_ to _all_ conditions of _all_ persons. Every attempt ever made to compel gold to answer the demands of money has been a disastrous failure. So long as a country enjoys continuous prosperity under a gold standard of value, it is all well enough. The people make use of an expanded volume of currency in the full faith that prosperity will continue and everything be smooth and right. But anon a _change_ comes, the nation is precipitated into conditions which require _more_ than its accumulations of gold to meet. _That_ being exhausted, it is _inevitable_ that representation be resorted to. The wealth in the form of gold not being adequate, and other wealth not having been used or accepted as money, paper representatives of it are the _only_ resort. So it appears that when an _emergency_ arises the people are _involuntarily_ pressed to the use of the principle of representation, which is the _only_ scientific thing that can be called money. So that while a paper representative of wealth is, _with everything else_, a product of labor, it is more than that; it is the embodiment and application of a principle, which other products of labor are not; and all principles are fundamental; are the basis of all permanent and all purely scientific things and truths, while wealth is the realized product of the outworking of principles, directed and appropriated by man for his use and convenience. The direct inquiry can now be made as to _what_ will _best perform_ what the people require of money; and money is that which can be used to _represent_ real values without an absolute _transfer_ of such values. The basis of all value of this country is our _present_ accumulated _real_ wealth and our _capacity_ to increase it, and this accumulation and the prospective increase may be _wholly_ represented by money and the nation never become bankrupt. A person may possess wealth to the amount of ten thousand dollars upon which he may issue his representatives of value or promises to pay that value. These representatives of value would circulate among those who believe in the capacity and intention of the utterer to give _up_ to them, _when_ demanded, that which they represent. Everybody by his individual right has the authority to issue such representatives of value, and no government has any right to prohibit their circulation; because the people, as individuals, have the right to take or refuse them. The issue of bank notes is upon the same principle, and so long as the government does not in substance _indorse_ these issues, the people have the _perfect_ right to deal in them—to receive and deliver them. But there is an insuperable objection—one which cannot be overcome by any governmental requirements—to these representatives being called the real money of the people, since circumstances over which _neither_ their utterers nor receivers can have _any_ control may render them valueless—may make it impossible for those who uttered them to redeem them—and their holders find themselves with _bits of paper_ representing _nothing_; but for which they parted with real value. So far as this condition is confined to individuals who had no other reason for receiving them, and no other assurance of their real value than the supposed _capacity_ and _intention_ of the uttering person or persons, it is _strictly_ a legitimate condition; and one with which the sufferers can find _no_ fault; since of their own free will and choice they received the utterers assurances that his representatives were of real value. An individual upon his personal judgment, without undue persuasion, accepts another’s representative; if it prove _bad_ he has _himself only_ to blame for the loss, as coming from an error of judgment; and _no power_ or _authority_ has any right to step in to compel the making of amends for this error. _This_ is the simple doctrine of the _rights_ of _individuals_, with which _no third party_ has any right to interfere after the occurrence of the fact. But when banks are organized under certain formula of law, framed by the people or their representatives through government, the people receive and pay out their issues—representatives of their value—_not_ because they have special confidence in the capacity and intention of the individuals who compose the management, _but_ because they _suppose_ the management has conformed to _those certain forms of law_ which are _intended_ to render them safe. In this way the government, at least indirectly, gives _credit_ to the bank, and _currency_ to its issues, and the people accept them _simply_ because the government has done so. But if these banks are mismanaged either ignorantly or intentionally, or managed by designing men, as often they are, who make use of the governmental sanction to swindle the people, as many times they have, _where_ can the people look for redress; _where should_ they look for redress? The government is justly responsible to the people for all such issues, since it did not require real security from the banks, and government should make reparation therefor. This is precisely our objection to _any_ and _all_ forms of bank issues. There can be _no_ arrangement made so _perfect_ in security to her people as to _guarantee_ them _absolutely_ against all hazard, that will permit the banks to make the profits which they seem to think they are entitled to make from the people. In _absolute_ security there can be _no_ profit. Bank profits demand the circulation of more notes than they have _real_ value to represent. Profits come only from speculating either upon the _confidence_ or the _money_ of the people, and government has _no_ right to _protect_ such _illegitimate_ and _unjust_ practices. Our present system of banking is a _swindle_ upon the people, which it is simply surprising that they endure as they have and do. For the banks to be permitted to filch from the people twenty-four million dollars per annum is an _outrageous villainy_ which, if comprehended by the people in its _true light_, could not exist _another year_. ’Tis true these banks complied with the law passed in a time of dire necessity, and that through them the government acquired the means to conduct the war. But did not the people themselves do even _more_ than furnish money, which was promised to be returned; did they not freely give their _lives_, which can never be returned, and which the government never thought of promising to either return or guarantee, and that, too, for the pitiful sum of thirteen dollars per month? What comparison is there between the sacrifices made by the two classes of people, the capitalists who have absorbed the wealth of the country and the laborers who still continue to give life, property and vitality _to_ the country. There is absolutely _no_ chance for a comparison; the distinction is _too_ great. It seems to me that if either class is entitled to superior consideration—to receive millions of the people’s money—it is the common people who so freely offered their _lives_ to save their country, instead of those who simply _loaned_ their money at enormous rates of interest, with the certain knowledge that it would be repaid. The present claims are too preposterous, and deceptive, and too unjust to be long continued. All bank notes in their ultimate effects are frauds upon the people, and their continuation as a circulating medium is only possible because that part of the people who suffer from them have not yet risen into a proper understanding of the question. The time is, however, near at hand when those who have reveled in the result, of the wear and tear of the muscle, and the sweat of the brow, of the common laborer, will be compelled to produce honestly and equitably everything they would enjoy. The substitute for all kinds of bank notes as the money for the people should be a _purely people’s money_—a _national currency_ whose basis of value would be the accumulated wealth of the country, and also its capacity for regularly increasing such wealth. Is there any reliance to be placed in a currency issued by an individual or a number of individuals through an incorporated bank, based upon his or their wealth, which is at all times liable to pass into the hands of other individuals? Yes, there is a presumptive reliance—an indefinite security—but the security is not perfect. In comparison with this security place that of a currency issued by the government, based upon the _entire_ wealth of the _whole_ country, which, no matter how much it might be changed about among the different persons comprising the nation by various contingencies, could never depart from the country; which fact would render it safe under any and all contingencies that could possibly arise, excepting alone the entire destruction of the country and its government by a foreign power; which contingency is not sufficiently imminent to cause any present alarm. A national currency _thus_ based would have not only _all the gold_ of the country as a basis, but also _all other kinds of wealth_. Is it not perfectly plain that such a money would be just so much better than common bank notes, with a one-third gold basis, as the total amount of the wealth of the country is greater than such amount of gold? It would be in the most complete sense the people’s money. It would be a system of mutual banking wherein every individual of the country would have an interest, instead of there being a vast number of mutual banking institutions, such as has been proposed by a person of profound financial ideas. As before stated, my objection to all systems of individual banking is that the _basis_ of their issues is at all times _liable_ to pass from the possession of such individuals; whereas, in a national currency—the _money_ of the people, _themselves_ in the aggregate the basis and security—there could be _no such_ liability; since, if _parts_ of the security pass from original to secondary hands, it is _still_ the basis of the currency, and could never be transferred beyond the jurisdiction of security by the operations of designing or incapable persons. By no possibility could there ever a loss occur to the holder of such a currency, except it be destroyed in his hands. Undoubtedly the _greenback_ was the _nearest_ approach to a _real_ money that any people of the earth ever made. We have only to observe how _admirably_ it has answered nearly all the purposes for which people require money, to be convinced that it has the very best—the most secure—basis that it is possible for a money to have. It stands representative of the capacity and willingness of the government—the representative of all the people—to pay. But it is one of the most _difficult_ of things for the people to divorce their minds from the idea that gold is the only possible, real money. Yet the _facts_ attaching to the greenback stand out in bold and indisputable relief, perfectly and entirely dispelling all basis for the idea. Because the greenback was the _first_ step toward a real money that the country ever took, which left gold entirely out of the question, the impression still remains with the people that a _return_ must be made to a gold basis; never stopping to observe how vastly superior the wealth basis is to what the gold basis would be. Bank note currency, or a currency issued by an individual or by a class of individuals, always carries along with itself the _idea_ and _need_ of redeemability. If, however, there is any thought among the people that the utterers cannot meet their _promises_ of redemption, at that _very_ time when, of _all_ others, _confidence_ is necessary to avoid _ruin_, they rush to prove the suspected incapacity; and generally they do prove it. The idea of, and necessity for, redeemability, is that which _most_ requires to be _divorced_ from money. Money—real money—should never require to be redeemed. It should always be just as valuable to retain possession of as anything could be into which it may be converted. Anything that requires to be redeemed in order to make it _permanently_ valuable or a representative of value is utterly unworthy the name of money, because it does not truly represent _real_ wealth. It is that currency of which there is doubt about the real wealth it pretends to represent which requires to be made redeemable before it will circulate; and _this_ fact proves _most_ conclusively that it is _not_ money in any true sense of that term: that is to say, it is not that which requires to be converted into substance. It is readily perceivable that a national currency having continually all the nation’s wealth, accumulated and prospective, as its basis, never needs to be redeemed. This _single_ consideration is of quite sufficient importance to _alone_ warrant its immediate adoption and use upon the standard of wealth. The gold standard is the flimsiest deception of which it is possible to imagine. The people’s talk of approaching a gold standard as the ultimate of appreciation is the _merest jeu d’esprit_. Gold is now selling at say 113. Suppose that during the next year its price should gradually decline to par, or, in the phraseology of the goldites, their country’s general credit should appreciate to par, would the process of appreciation _necessarily_ stop just at _that_ point? Why should it not just as reasonably _continue_ to appreciate, so that in another year gold would be below the par of the country’s credit? This simple analysis proves beyond _all_ cavil the arbitrariness of the gold standard of value. The credit of a country increases or diminishes without _any_ regard whatever to its gold producing or paying capacity. It is governed by its capacity for the _general_ production of _all_ kinds of wealth over and above its average consumption. It is just the same with a country as it is with an individual; the individual, to become wealthy and to have a good credit, must not necessarily ever have _any_ gold; but he must be able to produce or acquire more than he consumes by his general expenses. A country must proceed by the same process to become wealthy, and it is simply an _absurdity_ for people to talk of the _prosperity_ of the country when _high prices_ for _everything_ are induced and fostered by a system which restricts _general_ production in order that _special_ production may flourish. Individuals cannot get rich by trading among themselves, _no matter if they increase the price_ of their _wares ten per cent. every year_. Neither can all the individuals of a country do the same thing. What is required by both is increase in the quantity of what they trade in. It is not the price of what a people _have_ that constitutes their true wealth, but it is the _quantity_ of their commodities. A barrel of flour is possessed of no more real value if it cost twenty dollars instead of five. It will not maintain life a day longer, let the price even be a thousand dollars. Thus we arrive at the real basis of values—the real wealth—and I have introduced this, precisely for the purpose of showing the high-priced protectionists that they know nothing about _true_ values or _true_ economy, as well as to also show that there is _no_ real wealth except that which conduces to higher ends than its simple acquisition. Wealth as an end is despotism. Wealth as a means is humanitarianism. But to return from this departure to the main subject. For the idea of redeemability for money there should be substituted that of convertibility. A real money should at _all times_ be capable of being converted into _that_ of which it stands _representative_. And here we arrive at the last analysis of a real money. It will be readily seen how completely a national currency meets this requirement. It would be representative of the productive capacity of the country, and could always be converted into whatever portion or kind of its products might be required; or into the products of other countries which may be acquired by the direct exchange of our own products. What more than this can be demanded of money; or what better thing invented as money; or what more capable of inspiring and maintaining an even and legitimate confidence? National currency being the very best possible money, because it is not only the most convenient but also the most secure, there remains _nothing_ to be done but to _continue_ to so _acquaint the people_, until they become _convinced_ of the rapaciousness of those systems by which the _large_ majority are compelled to labor _all their lives_ for the _very select few_. There is no difficulty in arriving at all the initial points necessary to determine the amount required, how it should be distributed and kept in circulation, or how its circulation should be regulated. These are all practicalities of finance. But there is _one thing_ which has never yet received consideration, which is _absolutely necessary_ to make money meet _all_ the requirements of money, and at the same time to maintain a _fixed_ and _absolute_ value at all times and under all circumstances, which money never has had. From its lacking, have come all the various financial convulsions. And _this is_, an absolute measure of value. Can money be measured so that the same fixedness shall attach to it that attaches to everything else with which we have to do? Money itself has always been considered a measure of value; and it is this false stoppage and foundationless position that has made possible all financial discords, irregularities and inconsistencies. Does it appear to be a strange proposition that money should be measured? Why should not a dollar be just as absolute as a dollar as a pound is as a pound; or as a foot is as a foot; or as a gallon is as a gallon? A cord of wood contains one hundred and twenty-eight solid feet, or eight cord feet. It must _always_ be _eight_ feet in length, _four_ feet in height and _four_ feet in width, or some other multiples of one hundred and twenty-eight. A cord can _never_ be any more, _never_ any less than just that measurement. And the same rule holds of everything else with which we have to do; with quantity, time, space and motion. All these have fixed and unvarying modes of measurement. But money, the lever by which all these are moved, has been left to fluctuate as it would—to be moved by every different influence, so that in _many instances_ what should have brought contentment, peace and continuous prosperity, has bequeathed the direct reverse. It does not concern us that there are _more yards of cloth_ at one time than another, provided that _yard-sticks_ are all of the same length. But what _would_ concern us would be this: That if with increase of the _quantity_ of cloth the _length_ of the yard-sticks should increase proportionately; or with the _decrease_ of the quantity of flour the _pound_ should decrease in like proportion therewith. Now this is just what has always been true of money; its _real_ value _increases_ and _decreases_, just in proportion as those things which it professes to measure have increased or decreased in quantity. Instead of these things being exchanged or converted into something measured by as _fixed_ a _standard_ as they are, the attempt is made to measure them by _something_ which _constantly increases_ and _decreases_ in representative capacity. In other words, a dollar is not at all times one and the same thing. Sometimes it is but seventy–five cents, and sometimes a dollar and a half. That to say that seventy–five cents at one time possess the same representative power that a dollar and a half does at another time, which is in substance to say that money has no measure. Now what is desirable and indispensable is to give money a _fixed measurement_, which shall be _just_ as absolute in its measure of the value of money as the pound is in its measure of weight, or as the yard-stick is in its measure of distance. There never is any more cloth, though there be a thousand more yard-sticks. Nor is a yard-stick ever any longer or shorter, if the quantity to be measured is increased or decreased a thousand-fold. Now just to such a fixedness must money be reduced before it will subserve its best purposes and uses, and the only way this can be done is by that method which will also remove the _only possible_ objection there can be brought against such a national currency as is proposed. This objection is that by over-issues of currency its value would or might be depreciated. Let it be supposed that the country’s extremest need to meet the demands of the greatest amount of trade is a _billion dollars_ currency. At certain times there are greater and less demands for money, which, under our present practices, make a dollar, to-day, worth _four per cent. per annum_ interest, and to-morrow increase it to _ten per cent._ It must be remembered that we are now speaking of an _irredeemable currency_, the _representative_ of the _wealth_ of the nation: that the _government_ representing the nation has _uttered_ it, in behalf of _the people_, upon the _soundest_ and, in reality, the _only_ sure basis of value _any_ money _can have_—the productive power and capacity of the nation. An over-issue is the only thing to be guarded against. The government must be prohibited by some _absolute law_ from resorting to the process so well known in railroad management as the “_watering process_.” And this is to be accomplished in the following manner: This currency—this money—must be made convertible into a national bond, bearing such a rate of interest while in the hands of the people as shall be determined upon as “the true measure of value”—say three or four per cent.—which experience would necessarily determine as the true point of balance; and the bond also convertible into currency at the option of the holder. In other words, the people should demand that the Government issue one thousand million dollars in bonds, bearing three per cent. interest, payable in currency, and that it issue one thousand million dollars of circulating medium or money to be loaned to whomsoever deposits the bonds as collateral; all loans to be made at three per cent. per annum; to be for six months, with two renewals of three months each, one-half payable on each renewal. The principle underlying the time being that all credits should be settled with each year’s products. The operation of such a system can be very easily traced. Whenever there should be so much currency in circulation that it would be worth _less_ than four per cent., the surplus would at once be invested in the four per cent. interest-bearing national bond; and when business should revive and the demand for money to transact it should make money worth _more_ than four per cent., then bonds would be converted into currency again until the equilibrium should be re-established. And whenever the demand should be such that all the money would be converted, and money still be worth more than four per cent., then the government should issue enough to produce the equilibrium. Thus it is seen that the four per cent. or the three per cent. interest-bearing national bond becomes the _fixed measure_ of value for money. It would always be worth _just that amount_—_never_ any more; _never_ any less. The gallon measure always gives just the same quantity of molasses. The yard-stick always gives just the same quantity of cloth. The pound weight always gives just the same quantity of sugar. So, too, would this measure of money always give just the same amount of real wealth, or its representative, every day, week, month or year, whether applied to wealth in business, to bonds, or to money at interest. An oscillation would be perpetually maintained; first, conversion of currency into bonds; next, conversion of bonds into currency; and whenever the supply of currency should be deficient, _then the issue of more by the government to meet it_. Thus there would be a _people’s_ money regulated to _financial_ equilibrium, which is the _ultima thule_ of convenience for exchanging the products of industry. It may be remarked, parenthetically, here, that even three per cent. per annum interest is altogether too greatly in favor of capital. A careful calculation of interests and general increase of the nation’s wealth discovers that less than a two per cent. interest is required to make the capitalist and the laborer stand upon an equality. Had I the time I would be glad to present you some figures to show to what condition we are tending. I will simply remark, however, if capital continue to receive the present rates of interest for the next thirty-five years, at the end of that time it will have absorbed all the wealth of the country. That is to say, that interest compounded at the rate of 6 per cent. upon the present Banking Capital will amount to a sum larger than the present aggregate of wealth together with the same rate of increase which has governed it during the past, added thereto. Is not this a sufficiently alarming fact to cause people to stop and consider the despotism into which they are rapidly merging? Everybody who knows anything about the relations of money to the people must prefer such a money as we have indicated to any other kind. It is really the greenback system extended to _all uses_ for which money is required, and to which is given a _fixed measure_ of value. All people at present interested in national banks and high interest-paying bonds are constitutionally opposed to such a change in our money system. This, however, should not deter its introduction and use. The people’s welfare is what should be consulted, and made _the test_ of all propositions that are to become theirs to practice. National banks and all banks of issue, with their drain upon the people to make their immense profits, must be done away, and banks simply as depositories for the accommodation of the people, alone exist. The national bank and other currency would be gradually called in at the rate of, say ten per cent. a month. I may add in justification of this plan, that if the Government can loan three hundred millions to the banks for nothing, it can loan to the people for three per cent.; if at the same time it can pay three per cent. on its bonds and in currency, instead of six per cent. and in gold, it secures a new-found advantage. But one of the _chief_ benefits which would come to the people from the proposed currency would be the _interest_ which would accrue to the government—all the people—for the use of this money. In other words, _all_ the interest now paid to _banks of issue_ for _loans_, for the _same_ convenience should be paid to the government. A _part_ of the people, for the _use_ of money belonging to _all_ the people, themselves inclusive, would pay _interest_ to the government therefor. And what more legitimate method of governmental support than this, if by it all other means of taxation could be annulled? The interest now paid by the people of the country to the Banks and Capitalists would, twice over, pay all costs of maintaining the government. A three per cent. interest paid to the government on all loans the people required would not only relieve the people who produce wealth of one-half the interest they now pay, but also of all taxes of all kinds. Is not this a matter to be looked into in the most serious manner? With such a currency system _once_ inaugurated, the country would begin a gradual process of general prosperity. Wealth, instead of accumulating in a _few_ hands, would continually tend to an _equal_ distribution among _all_ producing people. A large part of the speculative mania would be rendered futile, and those now devoting all their time to _hatching schemes_ by which to defraud the producing classes of their wealth would be _compelled_ to turn producers themselves. It is calculated that one-tenth of the male population of this country is engaged in speculative pursuits. In other words, they ‘live and grow fat’ from those who are engaged in production. And that is our boasted equity, our equality. It should be the object of all reform to make a _nearer_ approach to a system of _complete_ justice and a _perfect_ equity. Any reform that does not base itself upon _such_ a proposition and whose outlook is not in this direction _is no reform_, and does not deserve the serious attention of any. There is scarcely an idea prevalent in the community of what true justice and equity consist. But it may be stated as follows: _No person has any just claim to the ownership of anything which he did not produce or which he did not acquire by an equitable exchange of something which he did produce._ Tested by _this_ rule, the accumulated wealth of the world is in unjust hands; it is held by those who have a _no better title_ thereto than if they had actually stolen it. It has been fraudulently acquired, and that is the word which best expresses the manner of its obtainment. And one of the most effective methods of remedying this growing evil is to attain to a true money system—one founded in the requirements to be met and based upon that which it is to represent—that which it is to be used to exchange. Anything that _departs_ from these standards is _not_ scientific money. That which _has_ these for its standards _is_ a scientific money. Aside from all that has been said, there is a general principle rising into the comprehension of humanity which _must of necessity_ dethrone that which has so long been worshiped as the money god. The day for arbitrary rule and standards is drawing to a close, whether they be standards of materiality or spirituality; of morals or intellect; of despotism or democracy. Gold _is_ an arbitrary money standard, and with all others of like character _must_ fall. The tendency of the world is _against it_, and its doom is _already_ sealed. It has been _weighed_ in the balance and found wanting. The interest of the common people, who should always hear every new Christ, demands a reform in our monetary and financial systems. We are aware, however, that there is a great deal of prejudice in their minds in favor of “hard money,” and they must be awakened to the fact that hard money is a myth—a play upon words—a deception practiced upon them by those who have played the part of “the appropriators of wealth” lo! these many years, and who would continue to filch _year_ after _year_ all that the “toiling millions” can compel nature to yield up to them. In this process the laboring classes are the mere avenues through which the earth pours its wealth into the coffers of the capitalists. Some object that the very numerous and intricate methods to which resort would be required would prove _unmanageable_, and that _corruption_ would _inevitably_ creep in and undermine its usefulness. Let such consider our almost perfect postal system, and how _well balanced_ are all its movements and checks, and find therein their answer. Would there be more intricacy in the proposed system than there now is in the present? Do not all national banks, though nominally distinct, _really_ have a common fountain head in government? Does not all their currency come from government? Suppose all these banks, instead of being independent institutions, were an organized system, having a common head, as the banks of New York City virtually have in the Clearing House, would not that be a condition so nearly related to the system which would be required as to show its entire practicability? Indeed, there is scarcely need that there should be a new department inaugurated to bring such a currency home to the people. Perhaps there never was a system operated in which there was _less_ proportionate loss through its executive officers than in our postal system. And this is because the _responsibility_ comes _home_ to the people. The postmaster is _always_ a resident of the _place_ in which he officiates, and, either with or without a civil service law, should be the _appointee_ of the citizens whom he is to serve; and, of course, would be a person possessing their special confidence. To such persons might the _care_ of the public money well be intrusted; and in _all places_ except cities a _single_ person could perform both the services of postmaster and of United States financial agent. Means can be easily devised to make all post offices offices for loaning, as they now sell post office stamps and money orders. In all that I have said my only purpose has been to endeavor to arrive at a proper understanding of the most important feature of governmental justice and uniform equity among all the people. All past systems have failed to secure this. The world has constantly witnessed the proceeds of the labors of the millions _aggregated_ in the hands of the few. This advantage which one class has possessed over another cannot long exist under the rapid spread of intelligence, which marks the present generation; and it behooves _this_ people to give _due_ consideration to _any_ scheme which proposes to lessen this advantage. And _most especially_ does it become the duty of the people, if there be such a thing as _principles_ of _finance_, to _find_ them out and cause them to be practically applied. In fine, and to resume, the idea of money must first be separated from that of the intrinsic value of gold, or any other commodity, and confined to the mere capacity of representing all commodities, and so of facilitating the exchanges of wealth. This, it has been abundantly demonstrated, can be as well, and for various reasons, better done by strips of paper, properly stamped and signed, than by gold or any other metal. In the next place, these strips of paper, signed by the Government, with the credit and wealth of the whole country, are better than individual promises; though the issuance of individual promises should not and need not be prohibited, as we do not now prohibit anybody from making or receiving private notes, drafts and checks. Again, the Government Money need not be redeemable, but only convertible into new strips of paper when the old ones are worn out, and into commodities when they are used in trade, and into other Government Securities bearing interest, as I have pointed out. Still again, money has also been held to be a correct measure of values. This it ought to be, indeed, but has never been so, because it has never been measured itself. Of what use would yard-sticks be, used for measuring cloth, but which had never themselves been measured by anything? The system which I have stated for measuring money itself is believed to be perfect. It is not the individual dollar, relatively to the half dollar or the hundred dollars, that has failed to be measured or fixed; but the rate of increase relatively to other values, of _all the Government currency afloat_. By the convertibility of any excess of issue sinking its value below a certain standard into interest-paying bonds, any over-issue is immediately absorbed, while a deficiency of issue will be revealed by the fact that absolutely no bonds will be sold. In this manner the whole operation will be self-adjusting from day to day; the value of the aggregate of Government money will be accurately measured and kept uniform; and any interest or temptation which the Government might have to an over-issue would be immediately neutralized by the absorption of such surplus into bonds, upon which the Government itself would be paying interest; or, in other words, assuming an unnecessary and useless burden, in the face of the people and of its own economies. Can anything more perfect be devised? If so, let us have it by all means; if not, let this device be adopted. A self-adjusting, self-regulating admeasurement of the value of money would make it a true measure of other values, and is a suggestion which, if it can be secured, is of unequaled importance. Another somewhat similar idea was glanced at in passing—that of a definite method of determining scientifically the equitable rate of interest. This I cannot stop now to explain. It will, however, only be when we come quite down to that basis, that the full value of this financial system will be experienced. Finally, in its basis, this system of Government money is money issued at the mere cost of printing and circulating; but by adjoining with it the idea of a complete, simple and exceedingly economical means of raising the revenue of the country, the three or four per cent. is paid to the treasury; that is to say, by the people individually to the same people in their collective capacity. Under this system all the various revenue officials and tax assessors and gatherers would be dispensed with, and a vast system of economy inaugurated, which, in a few years, would transpose us from a borrowing to a loaning nation, making us the financial example for all the world. This it also seems to me is another invaluable feature of the system, all of which I, however, respectfully submit to the decision of the people. The interests of humanity which are involved in this question are greater than are the interests of those who have assumed to _rule_ the world, and who are endeavoring to _fasten_ upon the people _despotism_, to escape from which would require the shedding of whole rivers of human blood and the destruction of the best evidences of our civilization, for which we have a perfect right to feel the greatest admiration. A _timely_ understanding of the money question would guarantee precisely the reverse of _all_ this, and cause humanity to take still _greater_ and more rapid _strides_ toward that perfect enlightenment which can alone thoroughly recognize the common brotherhood of the human race, toward which end all reform should be directed. ------------------------------------------------------------------------ TRANSCRIBER’S NOTES 1. Silently corrected obvious typographical errors and variations in spelling. 2. Retained archaic, non-standard, and uncertain spellings as printed. 3. Enclosed italics font in _underscores_. *** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK A SPEECH ON THE PRINCIPLES OF FINANCE *** Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will be renamed. Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S. copyright law means that no one owns a United States copyright in these works, so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it in the United States without permission and without paying copyright royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part of this license, apply to copying and distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG™ concept and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark, and may not be used if you charge for an eBook, except by following the terms of the trademark license, including paying royalties for use of the Project Gutenberg trademark. If you do not charge anything for copies of this eBook, complying with the trademark license is very easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as creation of derivative works, reports, performances and research. Project Gutenberg eBooks may be modified and printed and given away—you may do practically ANYTHING in the United States with eBooks not protected by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject to the trademark license, especially commercial redistribution. START: FULL LICENSE THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work (or any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at www.gutenberg.org/license. Section 1. General Terms of Use and Redistributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works 1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™ electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree to and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property (trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from the person or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in paragraph 1.E.8. 1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people who agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a few things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic works even without complying with the full terms of this agreement. See paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with Project Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this agreement and help preserve free future access to Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below. 1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the collection of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the individual works in the collection are in the public domain in the United States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in the United States and you are located in the United States, we do not claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing, performing, displaying or creating derivative works based on the work as long as all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of course, we hope that you will support the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting free access to electronic works by freely sharing Project Gutenberg™ works in compliance with the terms of this agreement for keeping the Project Gutenberg™ name associated with the work. You can easily comply with the terms of this agreement by keeping this work in the same format with its attached full Project Gutenberg™ License when you share it without charge with others. 1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the terms of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying, performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in any country other than the United States. 1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg: 1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must appear prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™ work (any work on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears, or with which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is accessed, displayed, performed, viewed, copied or distributed: This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States and most other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included with this eBook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you are not located in the United States, you will have to check the laws of the country where you are located before using this eBook. 1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is derived from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not contain a notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the copyright holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in the United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must comply either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 or obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project Gutenberg™ trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9. 1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works posted with the permission of the copyright holder found at the beginning of this work. 1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project Gutenberg™ License terms from this work, or any files containing a part of this work or any other work associated with Project Gutenberg™. 1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project Gutenberg™ License. 1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary, compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form, including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website (www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must include the full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1. 1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying, performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9. 1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works provided that: • You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation.” • You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who notifies you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that s/he does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg™ License. You must require such a user to return or destroy all copies of the works possessed in a physical medium and discontinue all use of and all access to other copies of Project Gutenberg™ works. • You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in the electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90 days of receipt of the work. • You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works. 1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work or group of works on different terms than are set forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing from the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set forth in Section 3 below. 1.F. 1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend considerable effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe and proofread works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating the Project Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project Gutenberg™ electronic works, and the medium on which they may be stored, may contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to, incomplete, inaccurate or corrupt data, transcription errors, a copyright or other intellectual property infringement, a defective or damaged disk or other medium, a computer virus, or computer codes that damage or cannot be read by your equipment. 1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except for the “Right of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph 1.F.3, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party distributing a Project Gutenberg™ electronic work under this agreement, disclaim all liability to you for damages, costs and expenses, including legal fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT LIABILITY, BREACH OF WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE FOUNDATION, THE TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE LIABLE TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL, PUNITIVE OR INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH DAMAGE. 1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you discover a defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it, you can receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by sending a written explanation to the person you received the work from. If you received the work on a physical medium, you must return the medium with your written explanation. The person or entity that provided you with the defective work may elect to provide a replacement copy in lieu of a refund. If you received the work electronically, the person or entity providing it to you may choose to give you a second opportunity to receive the work electronically in lieu of a refund. If the second copy is also defective, you may demand a refund in writing without further opportunities to fix the problem. 1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED, INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE. 1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of damages. If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement violates the law of the state applicable to this agreement, the agreement shall be interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or limitation permitted by the applicable state law. The invalidity or unenforceability of any provision of this agreement shall not void the remaining provisions. 1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the Foundation, the trademark owner, any agent or employee of the Foundation, anyone providing copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in accordance with this agreement, and any volunteers associated with the production, promotion and distribution of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works, harmless from all liability, costs and expenses, including legal fees, that arise directly or indirectly from any of the following which you do or cause to occur: (a) distribution of this or any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b) alteration, modification, or additions or deletions to any Project Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any Defect you cause. Section 2. Information about the Mission of Project Gutenberg™ Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers. It exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and donations from people in all walks of life. Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a secure and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help, see Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at www.gutenberg.org. Section 3. Information about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit 501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent permitted by U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws. The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West, Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact Section 4. Information about Donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without widespread public support and donations to carry out its mission of increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can be freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the widest array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small donations ($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax exempt status with the IRS. The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and keep up with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in locations where we have not received written confirmation of compliance. To SEND DONATIONS or determine the status of compliance for any particular state visit www.gutenberg.org/donate. While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where we have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no prohibition against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in such states who approach us with offers to donate. International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff. Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of other ways including checks, online payments and credit card donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate. Section 5. General Information About Project Gutenberg™ electronic works Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project Gutenberg™ concept of a library of electronic works that could be freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and distributed Project Gutenberg™ eBooks with only a loose network of volunteer support. Project Gutenberg™ eBooks are often created from several printed editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper edition. Most people start at our website which has the main PG search facility: www.gutenberg.org. This website includes information about Project Gutenberg™, including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how to subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.